By Roy C. Smith
Yesterday Sen. Bernie Sanders announced a seven-point plan
to rein in Wall Street greed once and for all by “breaking up the big banks and
re-establishing firewalls that separate risk-taking from traditional banking.”
Sanders is a populist, so of course his plan has a populist ring to it; but,
nevertheless the plan ought to be analyzed on the merits.
The key feature of the plan is to re-impose the 1933 Glass
Steagall Act that separated traditional banking from the securities business,
and which Congress repealed in 1999.
Much resisted by Wall Street when it was passed, the law changed the
competitive environment of the US financial system, but led to fifty years of
stability in banking and the development of robust capital markets that enabled
companies to obtain large amounts of financing for longer term, riskier
projects. By 1983, the US capital markets were the envy of the world and
efforts to import US financial market technology and knowhow to Europe and
Japan were well underway.
However, a global banking crisis began in 1984 with the
Federal Reserve’s takeover of Continental Illinois Bank, which failed because
of poor credit risk management and the consequent inability to roll over
maturing deposits from large financial institutions. Other large banks had
similar problems, so the crisis ultimately spread throughout the US, and then
migrated to Europe and Japan, where, like the US, a Glass Steagall-type of law
was also in place. Many banks had to be rescued by government funds during the
fifteen years or so that the crisis endured. However, the suppression of bank
lending imposed by government rescuers further shifted financial activity to
capital markets, where corporate needs during the relatively high growth years
of the 1980s and 1990s were fully met.
After the crisis, the banks realized that much of their
business with large corporations had been disintermediated to capital markets
where short term working capital could be raised more cheaply in commercial
paper, medium tern notes and bond markets in the US and the Euromarket. The
banks complained that their European competitors could participate fully in
capital markets, but they were losing business because they could not. Bank
loans, too, had become tradable in markets and had, partly through developments
in derivatives technology and capacity, become integrated into fixed-income
securities markets. Further, they argued, the Basel Accord that set a minimum
requirement for risk-adjusted capital adequacy had been agreed, so another
crisis was unlikely. It took several years to build support, but Glass Steagall
was repealed in 1999.
After the crisis in 2008, governments around the world once
again poured funds into large banks to prevent their failure and domino-like
contagion of the problem throughout the global financial system. The rescues involved several trillions
of dollars (mainly expended by central banks through lender-of-last resort and market
support activities) but stabilized the global financial system within a few
months.
Three observations of this
history are worth making.
One – Glass Steagall did not prevent the banking crisis in
the US and Japan in the 1980s and 1990s. Nor did the Basel Accord prevent the
crisis of 2008. Regulations don’t
always accomplish what they intend.
Two – the crises involved many performance-oriented banks
all around the world that were following similar business strategies in
competition with each other (though under an extensive regulatory regime).
These strategies focused on enabling companies and financial institutions to
take on risk and projects necessary for growth. It was not just because of
unlawful conduct, greed or incompetence that the crises occurred; it was much more
a matter of systemic market failure.
Three – government intervention was the only way that the
financial system could be saved from total collapse with much more severe
effects on the real economy than actually occurred. Too-Big-to-Fail policies
were indeed necessary; the government was the only source of funds to act as a
lender of last resort under such circumstances. Taxpayers actually made a
considerable return on their investment in such programs as TARP and
stabilization efforts by the Federal Reserve when these positions were unwound.
After the 2008 crisis when Congress was debating the
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (passed in 2010), a
re-imposition of Glass Steagall was considered. The arguments for it were that banks had become too big,
clumsy and herd-like (and greedy) to manage market risk well enough to avoid
the possibility of a future failure. The easiest way to reduce this risk would
be to make banks give up capital market activities. There was merit to the argument (that also applied in 1999)
but banks strongly resisted a one-size-fits-all policy that would permanently
bar banks from capital markets where three-fourths of the capital raised by
large corporations occurred. They also objected to a policy that would affect
them but not their foreign bank, or US non-bank, competitors.
Another argument was the extent to which bank lending had
become integrated with securities markets, making activities difficult and
expensive to separate, monitor, and enforce.
In the end, Dodd-Frank did not separate banking and
securities businesses, or force banks to reduce themselves to smaller sized
entities, but it did many other things that give much more power to regulators
to control the financial system, and limit risk taking by banks. Dodd-Frank
claims that it has eliminated Too-Big-to-Fail situations in the future, but it
attempts to do so not by restricting their bigness (except in terms of a
maximum market share of US bank deposits), but by restricting the amount of
risk of failure than the banks can take on.
Dodd-Franks defines “systemically important” banks as those
with assets greater than $50 billion (about 40 US banks), which are to be
subject to much tighter regulations than non-systemic banks. It also empowers
the government to designate “systemically important non-banks” (the so-called
“shadow banks”) and to regulate these the same as the large banks (four
non-banks have been designated as systemically important so far).
Dodd-Frank has many other provisions, including annual
stress tests necessary to pay dividends, regulation of proprietary trading
(“speculation,” which Bernie wants to tax), derivatives markets, executive
compensation, rating agencies (Bernie wants to force them to become non-profit
organizations), and consumer protection.
The irony of all this is that the weight on the big banks of
Dodd-Frank, Basel III (a tough upgrade of the original Basel Accord), and
various new national banking rules around the world, has made it very difficult
for banks to comply with all the new regulations and still make a return on
investment greater than their cost of equity capital. Almost all of the major banks have failed to produce a net positive
return on equity since 2009, so all are required to alter their basic business
models to enable improved returns.
Accordingly all banks have their eyes on one of their own,
Well Fargo, which has sailed through the regulatory changes relatively unscathed. Wells, essentially a retail and
consumer bank, never had a very extensive capital markets activity beyond what
was needed to service its mainly small and mid-sized corporate clientele. Today
it is the world’s largest bank by market capitalization, trades at 1.7 times
its book value (the rest trade at an average of about 1.0x), and generates 5%
net return on equity (after subtracting the cost of equity).
For big US banks like JP Morgan Chase, Citigroup and Bank of
America, the best approach to modifying their business models as a result of
regulatory changes may be to spin off to shareholders their riskier and more
capital intense investment banking units. Doing so would improve shareholder
returns, make regulators happier and enable their investors to participate in
two different, but separate, business models. Doing so would also, de facto, break up these banks as if Glass
Steagall had been restored.
Bernie Sanders probably has the right idea about what would
be good for the banks and everyone else. But, restoring Glass Steagall is not
necessary because Dodd Frank imposes so much regulatory weight on them that
their best way forward may be to break themselves up.
But, the banks haven’t done so
yet, and don’t seem to be inclined to do so.
Maybe things will be different
by the time of the election, or by 2017 when the new administration will be
pulling its legislative agenda together. But, if Bernie should somehow pull off
a win, then he still has to face a Republican House or Representatives (and
maybe a Republican Senate to), which will make his financial reform package
tough (probably impossible) to pass.
No comments:
Post a Comment